Jump to content

Late capitalism

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia

Late capitalism is a concept first used in print (in German) by the German social scientist Werner Sombart (1863-1941) in 1928, to describe the post-war capitalist order emerging at that time.[1] As a young man, Sombart was a socialist who associated with Marxist intellectuals and the German social-democratic party. As an academic who became well-known for his sociological writings, he had a critical-sympathetic attitude to the ideas of Karl Marx (but never became a true Marxist).[2] Sombart's influence played a big role in making "capitalism" a household word in Europe, as the name of a socio-economic system with a certain structure and dynamic, a mentality, a morality and a culture.

The use of the term "late capitalism" to describe the nature of the modern epoch already existed for four decades in continental Europe, before it began to be used by academics and journalists in the English-speaking world - via English translations of German Critical Theory texts, and especially via Ernest Mandel's 1972 book Late Capitalism published in English in 1975.[3] For many Western Marxist scholars since that time, the historical epoch of late capitalism starts with the outbreak of World War II in 1939/1940, and includes the post–World War II economic expansion, the era of neoliberalism and globalization, the 2007–2008 financial crisis and their aftermath in a multipolar world society. The term was not used by Marxist-Leninists, who used the concept of state monopoly capitalism originally formulated by Vladimir Lenin and Nikolai Bukharin.

The concept of "late capitalism" was never accepted by the majority of social scientists and historians, because it was considered that the expression was tinged with political bias towards capitalism, and because it remained unknowable or uncertain whether capitalism is "on its last legs", or "if and when it will end". The Russian revolutionary Vladimir Lenin famously declared in 1920, that there are no "absolutely hopeless situations" for capitalism; short of an anti-capitalist political revolution overthrowing the rule of the bourgeoisie, the system could always recover sooner of later.[4] Lenin considered that the fate of capitalism was essentially a political issue. The leaders of the Communist International founded in 1919 believed that with the first World War, a new world epoch of wars and revolutions had begun, and its programme defined state monopoly capitalism as the highest and final stage of capitalism.[5] Many non-Marxist historians and sociologists have preferred more neutral terms, such as the "late modern era" or "post-modern era". Some Continental and Anglo-saxon historians refer to late bourgeois society, in contrast to early bourgeois society in the 17th and 18th century and classical bourgeois society in the 19th and early 20th century.

According to Google N-gram viewer, the frequency of mentions per year of the term "late capitalism" in publications has increased steadily to 200% of the level in the 1960s. In 2017, an article in The Atlantic highlighted that the term "late capitalism" was again in vogue in America, as an ironic term for modern business culture.[6]

Intellectual history of the concept

[edit]

Sombart's legacy

[edit]

The term "late capitalism" (Spätkapitalismus) was first used by the German social scientist Werner Sombart in a 1928 publication[7] after he had completed his three-volume magnum opus Der Moderne Kapitalismus ["Modern Capitalism"], which was published from 1902 through 1927 (only the first volume of Sombart's Modern capitalism has been translated into English so far.[8]). Sombart divided capitalism into different historical stages of development:[9]

  • Proto-capitalist society from the early middle ages up to 1500 AD.
  • Early capitalism in 1500–1800.
  • The heyday of capitalism (Hochkapitalismus) from 1800 to World War I.
  • Late capitalism since then.[10]

Concluding his 1928 Zürich lecture on the transformations of capitalism, Sombart stated:

"Today we stand in a new epoch. It is obvious that [the beginning of] this new epoch will be defined by the [first] World War. What this period is called is to an extent arbitrary, although of course some names will be more appropriate in the given situation than others. I have suggested the term "late capitalism", because I know of no other expression which characterizes this era better. I hope that this term will be well-received; I am aware, of course, of how much aversion there is, particularly among academic colleagues, to accepting strange new terminology – as Max Weber once put it: "as if it were a question of using foreign toothbrushes." There is always a possibility that other expressions will prevail. But what is most important is not the name, but the phenomenon itself, the thesis that this is a new era of economic life, as well as the issue of the characteristics of this era. If agreement can be reached about that, I would consider my task fullfilled.[11]

Beyond a few articles and lectures, however, Sombart never completed any comprehensive treatise on late capitalism. His studies were disrupted by the new Nazi government when he was 70 years old (he died in 1941). Like many Germans intellectuals he hoped that Hitler's leadership would revive Germany from a decade of economic woes, social decay and misery, and he supported the Nazi party (while retaining much of his intellectual independence). Because of this fact and because of his portrayal of Jews and Judaism in some of his writings,[12] he was often regarded as a Nazi intellectual and as anti-semitic. It meant that after the war his writings and ideas largely vanished from university curriculae.[13] Only in the late 1980s[14] and 1990s did considerable scholarly interest for Sombart's intellectual legacy return.[15]

The interwar years and World War II

[edit]

The term "late capitalism" began to be used by socialists in continental Europe in the 1930s and 1940s.[16] At the end of World War II, leading American economists believed that the economic problems might become insurmountable. In their book Capitalism since World War II, Philip Armstrong, Andrew Glyn and John Harrison comment that:

"Paul Samuelson, who later wrote the bestselling economics textbook published in the postwar years, raised in 1943 the probability of a 'nightmarish combination of the worst features of inflation and deflation', fearing that 'there would be ushered in the greatest period of unemployment and industrial dislocation which any economy has ever faced' (Samuelson, 1943, p. 51). He was speaking, it should be remembered, about the United States, which was relatively unscathed by hostilities. […] Joseph Schumpeter, an eminent economist, summed up the mood of alarm of the early forties: 'The all but general opinion seems to be that capitalist methods will be unequal to the task of reconstruction,' He regarded it as 'not open to doubt that the decay of capitalist society is very far advanced' (Schumpeter, 1943, p, 120)."[17]

The post-war era

[edit]

The concept of "late capitalism" was used in the 1960s in Germany and Austria, by Western Marxists writing in the tradition of the Frankfurt School and Austromarxism. Leo Michielsen and Andre Gorz popularized the term "neo-capitalism" in France and Belgium, with new analyses of post-war capitalism.[18] Jacques Derrida preferred neo-capitalism to post- or late-capitalism.[19] Theodor Adorno preferred "late capitalism" over "industrial society," which was the theme of the 16th Congress of German Sociologists in 1968.[20] In 1971, Leo Kofler published a book called Technologische Rationalität im Spätkapitalismus (Technological Rationality in Late Capitalism). Claus Offe published his essay "Spätkapitalismus – Versuch einer Begriffsbestimmung" (Late Capitalism—an Attempt at a Conceptual Definition) in 1972.[21] In 1972, Alfred Sohn-Rethel published Die ökonomische Doppelnatur des Spätkapitalismus.[22] In 1973, Jürgen Habermas published his Legitimationsprobleme im Spätkapitalismus (Legitimacy problems in late capitalism).[23] In 1975, Ernest Mandel published his PhD thesis Late Capitalism in English at New Left Books. Herbert Marcuse also accepted the term.[24] In 1979, Volker Ronge published Bankpolitik im Spätkapitalismus: politische Selbstverwaltung des Kapitals?, a study of banking in late capitalism.[25] In 1981, Winfried Wolf and Michel Capron extended Mandel's analysis of the long recession in Spätkapitalismus in den achtziger Jahren.[26]

Immanuel Wallerstein believed that capitalism was in the process of being replaced by another world system.[27] The American literary critic and cultural theorist Frederic Jameson thought Rudolf Hilferding's term the latest stage of capitalism (jüngster Kapitalismus) perhaps more prudent and less prophetic-sounding[28] but Jameson often used "late capitalism" in his writings. Hegel's theme of "the end of history" was rekindled by Kojève in his Introduction to the Reading of Hegel. In modern usage, late capitalism often refers to a new mix of high-tech advances, the concentration of (speculative) financial capital, post-Fordism (transition of mass production in huge factories, as pioneered by Henry Ford, towards specialized markets based on small flexible manufacturing units),[29] and a growing income inequality.[30]

Ernest Mandel

[edit]

According to the Marxist economist Ernest Mandel, who popularised the term with his 1972 PhD dissertation, late-stage capitalism will be dominated by the machinations—or perhaps better, fluidities[clarification needed]—of financial capital;[31] and also by the increasing commodification and industrialisation of ever more inclusive sectors of human life. Mandel believed that "[f]ar from representing a 'post-industrial society', late capitalism [...] constitutes generalized universal industrialization for the first time in history".[32]

Up to the mid-1960s, Mandel preferred to use the term "neo-capitalism", which was most often used by intellectuals in Belgium and France around that time.[33] This term drew attention to new characteristics of capitalism, but at the time ultra-leftist Marxists objected to it, because, according to them, it might suggest that capitalism was no longer capitalism, and it might lead to reformist errors rather than the overthrow of capitalism.

In his work Late Capitalism, Mandel distinguished three periods in the development of the capitalist mode of production.

Ernest Mandel's book tried to provide an orthodox Marxist analysis and an empirically-based explanation of the postwar epoch in terms of Marx's theory of the laws of motion of the capitalist mode of production. In part, Mandel's analysis was a critique of Henryk Grossmann's breakdown theory, according to which capitalism would collapse after a series of business cycles. Mandel argued that important qualitative changes occurred in the functioning of the capitalist system during and after World War II. Between the sequence of business cycles and the ultimate collapse of capitalism, Mandel argued, there were epochs of faster and slower economic growth typically lasting 20 to 25 years. In several publications, Mandel analyzed the dynamics and results of the unexpected post-war boom, the long world recession of 1973 to 1982, the third world debt crisis, the 1987 stock crash and the long-term systemic crisis of late capitalism, as basis for his projections about the long-term prospects of world capitalism in the future.

In the tradition of the orthodox Marxists, Mandel tried to characterize the nature of the modern epoch as a whole, with reference to the main laws of motion of capitalism specified by Marx.[35] Mandel's aim was to explain the unexpected revival of capitalism after World War II, contrary to leftist prognostications, and the long economic boom which showed the fastest economic growth ever seen in human history.[36] His work has produced a new interest in the theory of long waves in economic development.[37]

Fredric Jameson

[edit]

Fredric Jameson borrowed Mandel's vision as a basis for his widely cited Postmodernism, or, the Cultural Logic of Late Capitalism.[38] Jameson's postmodernity involves a new mode of cultural production (developments in literature, film, fine art, video, social theory, etc.) which differs markedly from the preceding era of Modernism, particularly in its treatment of subject position, temporality and narrative.

In the modernist era, the dominant ideology was that society could be re-engineered on the basis of scientific and technical knowledge, and on the basis of a popular consensus about the meaning of progress. From the second half of the 20th century, however, modernism was gradually eclipsed by postmodernism, which is skeptical about social engineering and features a lack of consensus about the meaning of progress. In the wake of rapid technological and social change, all the old certainties have broken down. This begins to destabilize every part of life, making almost everything malleable, changeable, transient and impermanent.[citation needed]

Jameson argues that "every position on postmodernism today—whether apologia or stigmatization—is also...necessarily an implicitly or explicitly political stance on the nature of multinational capitalism today".[39] A section of Jameson's analysis has been reproduced on the Marxists Internet Archive. Jameson regards the late capitalist stage as a new and previously unparalleled development with a global reach—whether defined as a multinational or informational capitalism. At the same time, late capitalism diverges from Marx's prognosis for the final stage of capitalism.[40]

See also

[edit]

References

[edit]
  1. ^ Günther Chaloupek, ""Werner Sombarts 'Spätkapitalismus' und die langfristige Wirtschaftsentwicklung'". Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft. Vol. 22, Issue 3, 1996. Jahrgang (1996), pp. 385-400, at p. 386.
  2. ^ Friedrich Lenger, Werner Sombart 1863-1941: eine Biographie, 3rd edition. Munchen: Verlag C.H. Beck, 2012, chapter 4.
  3. ^ Ernest Mandel, Late capitalism. London: New Left Books, 1975.
  4. ^ Lenin, Vladimir Ilyich (July 19, 1920), Report On The International Situation And The Fundamental Tasks Of The Communist International, retrieved November 29, 2019
  5. ^ Lenin, Vladimir Ilyich (June 1916), Imperialism, the Highest Stage of Capitalism, retrieved November 29, 2019
  6. ^ Lowrey, Annie (May 1, 2017). "Why the Phrase 'Late Capitalism' Is Suddenly Everywhere: An investigation into a term that seems to perfectly capture the indignities and absurdities of the modern economy". The Atlantic. Retrieved November 29, 2019.
  7. ^ Specifically, Werner Sombart, "Die Wandlungen des Kapitalismus" [="The transformations of capitalism", a lecture given at the conference of the Vereins für Sozialpolitik in Zürich, on 13 September 1928]. In: Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, Vol. 28, 1928, pp. 243-256.
  8. ^ Werner Sombart, Modern Capitalism - Volume 1: The Pre-Capitalist Economy: A systematic historical depiction of Pan-European economic life from its origins to the present day, parts I and II. Wellington, New Zealand: K. A. Nitz Publishing, 2019 and 2023.
  9. ^ F.X. Sutton, "The social and economic philosophy of Werner Sombart: the sociology of capitalism", in: Harry Elmer Barnes (ed.), An introduction to the history of sociology. Chicago: University of Chicago Press,1948, pp. 316-331.
  10. ^ Werner Sombart, Die Zukunft des Kapitalismus[=The future of capitalism, a lecture dated 29 February 1932, edited by Elmar Altvater]. Berlin: Mimesis Verlag, 2017; See also Werner Sombart, "Capitalism". in Encyclopaedia of the Social Sciences, Volume 3. New York: Macmillan, 1930, pp. 195-208.
  11. ^ Werner Sombart, "Die Wandlungen des Kapitalismus" [Vortrag, gehalten auf der Tagung des Vereins für Sozialpolitik zu Zürich am 13e September 1928]. In: Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, Vol. 28, pp. 243-256, at pp. 255-256.
  12. ^ See for example: Werner Sombart, The Jews and modern capitalism. Kitchener: Batoche Books, 2001.
  13. ^ Reiner Grundmann and Nico Stehr, "Why Is Werner Sombart Not Part of the Core of Classical Sociology?: From Fame to (Near) Oblivion." Journal of Classical Sociology, Volume 1, Issue 2, 2001.
  14. ^ Bernhard vom Brocke (ed.), Sombart's "Moderner Kapitalismus: Materialien zur Kritik und Rezeption. München: Deutscher Taschenbuch Verlag, 1987.
  15. ^ Jürgen Backhaus (ed.), Werner Sombart (1863-1941), Social scientist. Vol. 1: His life and Work, Vol. 2: His Theoretical Approach Reconsidered, Vol. 3: Then and Now. Weimar bei Marburg: Metropolis Verlag, 1996; Jürgen Backhaus (ed.), Werner Sombart (1863 - 1941) - Klassiker der Sozialwissenschaften Eine kritische Bestandsaufnahme. Marburg: Metropolis Verlag, 2000; Nico Stehr & Reiner Grundmann (eds.), Werner Sombart: Economic Life in the Modern Age. New Brunswick: Transaction, 2001.
  16. ^ See, for example, Natalie Moszkowska's Zur Dynamik des Spätkapitalismus. Zurich: Verlag Der Aufbruch, 1943.
  17. ^ Philip Armstrong, Andrew Glyn and John Harrison, Capitalism since World War II: the making and breakup of the great boom. London: Fontana paperbacks, 1984, p. 23. Republished in a new edition, with a rewrite of Part III, as: Philip Armstrong, Andrew Glyn and John Harrison, Capitalism since 1945. Oxford: Blackwell, 1991, pp. 4-5. The references are to Paul Samuelson, "Full employment after the war" and Joseph Schumpeter, "Capitalism in the post-war world", both included in S. Harris (ed.), Post-war economic problems. New York: McGraw-Hill, 1943.
  18. ^ Leo Michielsen, Neo-kapitalisme. Brussel: Jacquemotte Stichting, 1969. André Gorz, Stratégie ouvriére et néocapitalisme, Paris: Le Seuil, 1964.
  19. ^ Catherine Malabou/Jacques Derrida, Counterpath (2004) p. 114–115
  20. ^ Theodor W. Adorno (ed.) Spätkapitalismus oder Industriegesellschaft. Verhandlungen des 16. Deutschen Soziologentages. Stuttgart, 1969.
  21. ^ Claus Offe, Strukturprobleme ds kapitalistischen Staates. Frankfurt: Suhrkamp, 1972, pp. 7–25.
  22. ^ Alfred Sohn-Rethel, Die ökonomische Doppelnatur des Spätkapitalismus. Luchterhand: Darmstad/Nieuwied, 1972.
  23. ^ Jürgen Habermas, Legitimationsprobleme im Spätkapitalismus Frankfurt: Suhrkamp, 1973.
  24. ^ Herbert Marcuse, "Protosocialism and Late Capitalism: Toward a Theoretical Synthesis Based on Bahro's Analysis". International Journal of Politics, Vol. 10 No. 2/3, Summer-Fall 1980, 25–48.
  25. ^ Volker Ronge, Bankpolitik im Spätkapitalismus: politische Selbstverwaltung des Kapitals? Frankfurt am Main : Suhrkamp, 1979.
  26. ^ Winfried Wolf and Michel Capron, Spätkapitalismus in den achtziger Jahren. Bilanz der Weltwirtschaftsrezession 1980/81; die Strukturkrise der Autoindustrie und der Stahlbranche. Frankfurt/Main : ISP, 1981.
  27. ^ Michele Dillon, Introduction to Sociological Theory (2009) p. 39.
  28. ^ M. Hardt/K. Weeks eds., The Jameson Reader (2000) p. 257
  29. ^ "Post-Fordism Definition & Meaning".
  30. ^ Harry Targ, Challenging late Capitalism, Neoliberal Globalization, & Militarism. Carl Davidson, 2006, p. 15–26
  31. ^ The Jameson Reader p. 268–269
  32. ^ Ernest Mandel, Late Capitalism (London: Humanities Press, 1975) p. 387
  33. ^ Ernest Mandel, The economics of neocapitalism. Socialist Register 1964, pp. 56–67.
  34. ^ The Jameson Reader p. 165–166
  35. ^ The Jameson Reader, p. 216–217
  36. ^ The Jameson Reader, p. 257
  37. ^ Grace K. Hong, The Ruptures of American Capital (2006) p. 152
  38. ^ Postmodernism, or, the Cultural Logic of Late Capitalism. Durham, NC: Duke University Press. 1991. pp. 438. ISBN 8190340328. OCLC 948832273.
  39. ^ The Jameson Reader, p. 190
  40. ^ The Jameson Reader p. 164–171

Further reading

[edit]
[edit]